The main results of the paper:
- The Beveridge Curve represents a long-run supply condition
- Short run deviations represent periods of disequilibrium, either over or under supply
- Using a years of oversupply metric, the observation of 2007-2008 was an all-time high of 0.995 years of oversupply, more than three times the previous peak of 0.285 in 1973-1974.
- Generally, oversupply is a phenomena in the rental market
- Oversupply in the rental market is twice as volatile as in the owner-occupied market
- Oversupply first shows up in the rental market
- Oversupply in the owner-occupied market is related to house prices, reinforcing the idea that short run deviations in house prices from fundamentals (such as bubbles) can lead to periods of oversupply
The primary change from the earlier results is that instead of doing the fairly ad-hoc HP filter, I have gone ahead and estimated the model using biannual data. In my opinion this gives a better estimation. In addition to the new estimation I have also found some interesting results relating oversupply of houses to house prices. I will go over those results in my next entry, for now I give an overview of my previous results under the new estimation.
The main idea of the Beveridge curve is that it represents the long-run equilibrium in the housing market. The Beveridge curve has its origins in labour economics, where Lord Beveridge found a negative relationship between the unemployment rate and the amount of job vacancies. For an example, see Rob Shimer's website. In the housing market I have found a negative relationship between the rate of household formation and the residential vacancy rate. I deem this negative relationship the Beveridge curve in the housing market. The Beveridge curve relationship exists in the owner-occupied market, the rental market, and the overall market irrsepective of ownership. Figure 4 from the paper, shown here below, shows the relationship for the overall house market. There is a clear and statistically significant negative relationship and the R-squared from a linear regression is 0.626.




One point that I cannot stress enough is that what we are currently facing is a huge oversupply of housing, irrespective of whether it is rental or owner-occupied housing. As I stated in the earlier post there is actually more oversupply in the rental market. To see this, below is figure 12 from the paper. The metric is years of oversupply in terms of the total rate of household formation, so that we are comparing apples to apples. There are several striking features in this figure:
- Generally, oversupply is a phenomena in the rental market
- Oversupply in the rental market is twice as volatile as in the owner-occupied market
- Oversupply first shows up in the rental market
